The yawning gap between rich and
poor is at its widest in Latin America. Nowhere on earth is there less equal distribution
of wealth or such a striking degree of social inequality. Although overall poverty levels
are lower than those of other developing regions, they are still extremely high and,
distressingly, they are higher today overall than they were before the debt crisis of the
1980s. Nearly a decade of growth and continued economic development has failed to correct
the imbalance.
During the so-called "lost
decade"of the 1980s the region lost so much ground that in 1990 poverty levels were
even higher than those at the start of the 1970s. Indicators have improved with a
resumption of economic growth in the 1990s, but not nearly enough. In 1980, 35% of all
households were poor. By 1990, that figure had risen to 41% and was still 39% in 1994.
The effort to account for these
trends has sparked a great deal of controversy as to how macroeconomic performance,
structural reform and globalization influence social indicators. A number of studies have
confirmed that poverty tends to decline in the presence of economic growth. Others point
to a growing amount of evidence that economic liberalization and globalization have lead
to a deterioration in income distribution. In a number of recent studies ECLAC has
attributed this deterioration in income distribution to the widening wage gap between
highly-skilled and unskilled workers in a context of sluggish rates of job creation for
skilled occupations. According to ILO estimates, eight out of every ten new jobs in the
1990s are in poor-quality occupations within the informal sector.
In Latin America, one possible
explanation has to do with the fact that the trade liberalization process was launched on
the heels of a decade-long downturn in social expenditure, and the shift in labour demand
towards highly-skilled manpower consequently ran up against an inelastic supply of such
workers. Furthermore, no serious effort was made to match supply and demand for different
skill levels. Another hypothesis focuses on the argument that the tendency towards
currency overvaluations and steps taken to open up the capital account, among other reform
measures, created patterns of growth in which exports rose more slowly than imports and
the production of tradeable goods was less buoyant that non-tradeable goods and services,
thereby skewing labour demands. Macroeconomic policy management has also gone through
abrupt stop-and-go cycles which, in combination with fluctuations in capital flows, has
caused growth rates to remain highly volatile, thereby interfering with the creation of
more stable types of jobs.
One of the major challenges facing
Latin America today is to demonstrate that the new development model is compatible with a
gradual correction of the region's social inequity. Failure to attain this objective
could undermine political foundations of the reform process, largely because the
restoration of macroeconomic stability has been viewed favorably by the general public.
Another equally serious hazard is that such a failure might generate social tensions which
could create problems of governance and erode the political consensus that has made it
possible for democracy to thrive in the region, which is unquestionably one of the major
achievements witnessed in recent years.
Many experts conclude that economic
liberalization policies need to be coupled with more ambitious, efficient and effective
social policies, known as the "second generation" reforms. Some services have
already been been opened up to the private sector, while services that remain the
responsibility of the State are being decentralized, new results-oriented public
management schemes are being devised, public-sector service providers are being given
effective autonomy, and mechanisms are being established to give the general public a role
in overseeing government management.
These reforms offer promising
opportunities but they are not a panacea: they need to be pragmatic and based on a
gradual, learning-by-doing approach. The participation of the private sector cannot always
serve as a substitute for government-provided services, so it is advisable to design mixed
systems in which public and private agents can compete with one another. Where competition
is not a viable option efforts must be made to upgrade public services through
decentralization, implementing results-based public management systems, granting autonomy
to public service providers and allowing the citizenry to play a role in overseeing these
activities. These measures are essential, and perhaps the most basic, elements of any
social service reform initiative.