United Nations
Commission on Sustainable Development

Background Paper


                         RESEARCH ON LINKAGES BETWEEN
                TRADE, ENVIRONMENT AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT


                             A preliminary note* 


*     This note describes preliminary results of initial work undertaken for
the preparation of a background paper for the Commission on Sustainable
Development on research on trade, environment and development carried out by
international organizations, academic institutions and non-governmental
organizations. It is being issued to invite comments and the provision of
additional information. The final version of the background paper will be
submitted to the Commission at its fifth session in 1997.    

      This note reflects several views, all of which may not necessarily
correspond to those of the UNCTAD secretariat. 


                                 CONTENTS

                                                              Paragraphs  Page

INTRODUCTION .....................................              1 - 4    4 - 5

I.        THE NOTION OF SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT .............  5 - 12    5 - 6
          WITHIN THE CURRENT TRADE AND ENVIRONMENT
          DEBATE

II.       REVIEW OF OUTSTANDING ISSUES IN TRADE-............. 13 - 95    7 -26
          ENVIRONMENT RELATED POLICIES

          A.   Trade liberalisation and the environment ..... 13 - 28    7 -10

          B.   Processes and production methods ............. 29 - 43   10 -14
          
               1.    Conceptual and practical issues related to
                     PPM-based environmental-trade measures ..29 - 38   10 -13
          
               2.    Environmental taxes and border tax
                     adjustment ..............................39 - 43   13 -14

          C.   Competitiveness issues ....................... 44 - 56   14 -17

          D.   Harmonisation of standards ................... 57 - 67   17 -18

          E.   Multilateral environmental agreements ........ 68 - 82   19 -23

               1.    Compatibility and consistency of trade
                     measures in MEAs with WTO rules ........ 69 - 75   19 -20

               2.    Criteria for MEAs ...................... 76 - 82   21 -23

          F.   Trade-related aspects of intellectual property
               rights (TRIPs) ............................... 83 - 95   23 -27

               1.    Implications for developing countries..  89 - 95   24 -27

III.      PRELIMINARY CONCLUSIONS .......................... 96 - 108   27 -29


                                 INTRODUCTION

1.    The Commission on Sustainable Development, at its third session, invited
"UNCTAD, the task manager for trade and environment, in cooperation with UNEP,
the World Trade Organization, FAO, WHO, the Department for Policy Coordination
and Sustainable Development of the United Nations Secretariat and other
appropriate institutions, to prepare a background paper for the Commission
that would review the growing volume of research on trade, environment and
sustainable development linkages carried out by international organizations,
as well as academic institutions and non-governmental organizations in
developed and developing countries, including within the framework of projects
supported by international and bilateral aid agencies with a view to
identifying possible gaps, including through the use of independent trade and
environment expert groups" (paragraph 60 of chapter I of the report of the
Commission on Sustainable Development on its third session). 1/

2.    The background paper will be made available to the Commission at its
fifth session in 1997. To initiate this study, the UNCTAD secretariat has
requested information from over 150 international organizations, academic
institutions and NGOs, of which 40 responded. 2/ The present note is aimed
at inviting comments and additional information, in particular from academic
institutions and non-governmental organizations, including those which may not
have been contacted, so as to allow the UNCTAD secretariat, in cooperation
with other international organizations, to complete the background note as
requested by the Commission. 

3.    The report covers the following broad areas: sustainability, trade
policies and the environment, environmental policies with trade effects, and
major GATT/WTO issues. However, an analysis of the contents of the papers and
documents received against the background of the main issues raised in reports
on trade, environment and development prepared for the Commission in 1995
(E/CN.17/1995/12) and 1996 (E/CN/17/1996/8 and Add.1), as well as issues which
have been discussed in the Committee on Trade and Environment (CTE) of the
World Trade Organization and UNCTAD's Ad Hoc Working Group on Trade,
Environment and Development, reveals that issues such as market access,
domestically prohibited goods, services and TRIPs are hardly covered.  

4.    This paper is structured within the framework of two main research
paradigms. By way of an introduction, the notion of sustainable development
within the context of the current trade-environment debate is briefly
examined. This is followed by an examination of major trade policy
developments and their linkages with environmental issues and sustainable
development, highlighting six focal issues - trade liberalisation, processes
and production methods, competitiveness, harmonisation of standards,
multilateral environmental agreements (MEAs), and trade-related aspects of
intellectual property rights (TRIPs). The final section draws some preliminary
conclusions in light of the literature reviewed. 

               I. THE NOTION OF SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT WITHIN 
                   THE CURRENT TRADE AND ENVIRONMENT DEBATE 

5.    The concept of sustainable development, introduced and defined by the
World Commission on Environment and Development in the Brundtland Report in
1987, has not made much headway in terms of its development and
operationalisation, evolving rather in the absence of a common frame of
reference (International Institute for Sustainable Development, 1992; FAO,
1994). 

6.    The European Community has called for further actions on the environment
to be based on the principles of sustainable development, preventive and
precautionary action and shared responsibility through its Fifth Action
Programme. Similarly, the Maastricht Treaty is also committed to the promotion
of sustainable growth with due respect to the environment (Commission of the
European Communities, 1992).
 
7.    Some empirical studies have been carried out on the subject of
sustainable development. In this context, two recent FAO studies which
complement each other can be mentioned. The first one examines the underlying
implications of sustainable development for economic, social and legal
policies, with a major emphasis on the notions of sustainability and
sustainable development in agriculture. It is argued that, in spite of the
multiplicity of definitions in the existing literature, only very few, which
are operational, can provide proper policy guidance towards achieving the
desired goal of sustainable development; further to which, there is no general
agreement at present on any operational definition of sustainable development
(Markandya, 1994). The second study, focusing on agricultural sustainability,
attempts from an economic standpoint to clarify basic concepts which can be
applied in the analysis of environmental issues. The alternative definitions
of and criteria for sustainability which refer to "resilience at the agro-
system level", "maintaining the capital stock", and "the implications of
entropy and co-evolutionary development" are discussed. Examples of
unsustainable agricultural practices are considered, and the causes of
unsustainable resource management, namely population growth, property rights,
poverty, prices and government policy, are assessed (Young and Burton, 1992).

8.    At a different level of analysis, the substitutability of environmental
resources raises serious questions in respect of the feasibility and
desirability of technology replacing natural resources and doing so without
jeopardising the stability of the environmental system with which the economy
interacts. For this reason, FAO argues that an approach is needed that pays
attention to the vulnerability of the eco-sphere or its capacity to absorb
economic activity, pointing out the need to search for integral strategies
that serve both development and environment and to resist the notion that the
two need necessarily be in conflict (FAO, 1994).
9.    It can be deduced from the above that environment and sustainable
development are closely related concepts, although sustainable agricultural
and rural development is generally perceived as being a wider concept,
encompassing environmental, technological, economic and social dimensions. 

10.   The International Institute for Sustainable Development (IISD) calls for
a broader view of sustainability combining ecological, economic and socio-
cultural objectives which would reflect the compromises that have to be made
in developing policy options and making decisions. It is argued that the task
would be to develop analytical tools and indicators and to offer policy
options to decision-makers. The problem is that beyond indicators there are
necessary trade-offs between objectives, and this is where the issue of
sustainable development assumes importance (IISD, 1994).

11.   The concept of sustainable development, as stated in the Brundtland
Report, also includes the notion of poverty alleviation, particularly meeting
basic needs for all and extending equal opportunity to fulfil the aspirations
of the poor towards a better life. It further states that a world in which
poverty is endemic will always be prone to ecological and other disasters.
Further it clearly includes the notion that economic growth and equity are
essential facets of sustainable development. Such equity according to the
report would be aided by political systems that secure effective citizen
participation in decision-making and by greater democracy in international
decision-making. Serious gaps in research exist on these other facets of
sustainable development: viz promoting economic growth while restoring inter-
and intra-generational equity, poverty alleviation and restoring "greater
democracy in international decision-making" (World Commission on Environment
and Development, 1987)

12.   There is a need to undertake more work on the environmental impacts of
changes in agricultural, forestry and other practices. With regard to monetary
accounts, a number of methodological problems remain to be solved,
particularly, in the treatment of environmental protection expenditures, the
treatment of pollution damage, and the treatment of depreciation and
degradation of the natural resource base. Physical data bases are important
for both physical and monetary accounting systems. This is an area where
developing countries need support, particularly from developed countries
(Markandya, FAO, 1994). The IISD points to the need to analyse the effects of
the functioning of commodity markets on sustainable development (IISD, 1995).
Studies are required to analyse how trade in certain agricultural commodities
will affect patterns of land use and the species and habitats that depend on
them (Birdlife International, February 1996). Furthermore, Birdlife
International points out that new approaches to promoting sustainable resource
exploitation whilst penalising trade which is not sustainable should be
considered. OECD calls for more multi-disciplinary work on trade and
environment issues with a view to promoting the compatibility and mutual
reinforcement of trade and environmental policies in practice in order to
contribute to sustainable development (OECD, 1995).




            II. REVIEW OF OUTSTANDING ISSUES IN TRADE-ENVIRONMENT 
                               RELATED POLICIES

                  A. Trade liberalisation and the environment

13.   An IMF study, quoting from Grossman and Krueger (1991), points out that
liberalisation generally leads to an increase in the scale of activity,
resulting in an increase in resource use. Secondly, liberalisation and its
induced relative price changes lead to changes in the composition of output.
Thirdly, liberalisation typically induces changes in the techniques of
production (IMF, Vol. II, 1994). 

14.   Positive effects of trade liberalisation on the environment and
sustainable development can be summarised as follows: (a) a
composition/structural effect: improved efficiency of resource allocation and
use; (b) a regulatory effect: reduction or removal of environmentally damaging
trade restrictions; (c) a technology effect: improvements in and the transfer
of environmentally friendly technology, reducing pollution per unit of output;
(d) a product effect: increased international availability of environmentally
friendly goods and services; (e) a scale effect: increased opportunities for
sustainable growth and development and economic diversification, and
additional resources to use for environmental protection (Grossman and Krueger
1991, OECD 1994). 

15.   Similarly, negative environmental effects can arise on account of a
number of factors (for example, Leonard 1998, Tobey 1990, Grossman and Krueger
1991, Dean 1992, Birdsall and Wheeler 1992, WWF 1992, French 1993, Repetto
1994, Lopez 1994): (a) adverse composition/structural effects result from
trade liberalization in the form of misallocation of productive resources and
the inoptimal composition of output if environmental assets are not properly
valued and internalized in market prices; (b) negative regulatory effects may
arise if trade liberalization and the adoption of stricter multilateral rules
regulating tariff and non-tariff trade barriers undermine environmental
policy-making; (c) product effects can be negative to the extent that trade
liberalisation contributes to increased trade in environmentally harmful or
sensitive products; (d) adverse technology effects may occur if trade leads to
the spread of environmentally harmful technologies, through, for example,
industries migrating to "pollution havens"; and (e) the scale effects of trade
liberalisation may be negative if environmental costs of production are not
fully internalized and reflected correctly in market prices.  

16.   In general terms, the Uruguay Round Agreement is expected to result in
significant reductions in the level of bound import tariffs on industrial
products and an increase in the coverage of bindings. From a resource
management point of view, in some cases the reduction of import tariffs may
stimulate demand for commodities or products, thus increasing exploitative
pressure on resources which may already be managed in an unsustainable manner.
In other cases tariff cuts may lead to prices which more accurately reflect
resource and environmental costs of a traded item, and this may encourage the
use of less environmentally damaging commodities or products. The elimination
of tariff escalation offers opportunities for reducing the net impact of
international trade on the global environment, while the practice of charging
progressively higher tariffs on more processed products has exacerbated
developing countries' economic dependence on exports of raw materials,
increasing exploitative pressure on these resources. Tariff escalation may
further stimulate the demand for natural resouces by ensuring that economic
benefits of value-added processing accrue to the consuming countries. On the
other hand, the abolition of tariff escalation and the generally improved
access to developed country markets for manufactured and processed goods from
developing countries, could substantially reduce pressures on those countries'
natural resource bases (WWF, February 1994). 

17.   Beyond environmental effects of high tariffs alone, tariff escalation
has its main effects through its influence on the location of production,
which is typically associated with processing of primary commodities, for
example trade in forestry, mining, fisheries and agricultural products.

18.   Tariff escalation encourages the expansion of downstream processing
industries in the importing country and a corresponding contraction in third
countries. If third countries concerned are also the main suppliers to the
world market of raw materials, tariff escalation may increase pressure there
to expand output of raw materials for export in order to maintain foreign
exchange earnings, causing environmental damage, possibly beyond sustainable
limits. A complementary effect stems from constraining value-added in third
countries, particularly when they are the raw material exporters, which limits
the resources available to reduce poverty and pay for better environmental
protection. Furthermore, tariff escalation also reinforces other obstacles to
economic diversification (WTO Bulletin, March 1995).

19.   The IMF (Vol. II, 1994) notes that a number of empirical studies (Runge
1993, Anderson 1992, Pearce and Watford 1993) show that in practice trade
liberalisation improves the environment instead of being harmful to it. In the
event of adverse environmental effects, the primary cause is to be attributed
not to trade liberalisation but to the failure of markets and Governments to
price environmental resources appropriately. In the same context, the widely
held view that environmental problems are caused by production and consumption
activities and not by international trade needs to be underlined (WTO, 1995).
Empirical evidence (Runge 1993) lends support to the fact that many
environmental problems associated with agriculture stem from the same policies
that result in trade distortions. This is the case of price support and trade
protection policies and water, fertilizer and pesticide subsidies, as applied
to selected agricultural commodities in industrial countries, which result in
reduced crop variety, chemical pollution, soil erosion and depletion, and
pollution of water supplies. 

20.   Further evidence shows that numerous internationally traded crops, for
example coffee, cocoa and tea, that can be beneficial for soil stability have
been affected by adverse terms-of-trade effects or the anti-export bias of
government policies. On the  other hand, certain commodities, such as cattle
and other crops like maize, cassava and groundnuts, subjected to special trade
arrangements can be environmentally damaging (IMF, Vol II. 1994 quoting Pearce
and Watford 1993). 


21.   Studies analysing the adverse effects of trade liberalisation indicate,
as in the case of Ghana, a trade-off between the direct increase in output
from extending the margin of cultivation and the decrease in agricultural
productivity from the reduction in the use of biomass. An estimation of the
effects of a decrease in agricultural export taxes and a decrease in
industrial tariffs points to a decline in real income in each case due to a
deterioration of the environment associated with extensive exploitation of the
biomass (IMF, Vol II, 1994 quoting Lopez 1993). 

22.   Another study analysing the effects of Indonesia's log export ban aimed
at curtailing deforestation shows that, given the low efficiency of the wood-
processing industry, which benefited from a subsidy as a result of the fall in
domestic log prices which followed the ban, the adverse environmental
consequences of the subsidy implicit in the ban were significant. It is
pointed out that these could have been avoided if the ban, whose price effects
led to the subsidization of the local processing industry, had been
substituted instead by an appropriate production tax (IMF, Vol II, 1994
quoting Braga 1992).

23.   The agricultural sector has turned out to be a subject of serious
environmental concern, as it provides many examples of market failures
combined with trade restricting and distorting policies, resulting in adverse
environmental effects. Studies carried out to date show, on the one hand,
direct, negative and often significant environmental effects stemming from
market access restrictions, domestic support policies and export subsidies,
and on the other hand, those stemming from high taxation of agricultural
production relative to other economic activities - both directly and
indirectly through exchange rate over-valuation and import protection of other
sectors of activity. As a matter of fact, adverse environmental effects are
associated with a wide range of specific policies applied to protect
agricultural production. For example, production subsidies can lead to
deforestation, input subsidies can encourage more intensive use of agro-
chemicals, and multiple trade-restrictive measures can cause compounded
environmental damage in various ways - water, air and soil pollution. As far
as agricultural export subsidies are concerned, they can produce the following
effects: depress prices of agricultural products on world markets, especially
in targeted export markets; reduce farm incomes; extend low-yielding farming
and ranching to ecologically vulnerable tropical forests and; aggravate rural
poverty (WTO, 1995, quoting Runge 1994, Repetto, 1993 and 1994, Anderson
1992). 

24.   In the industrial sector, evidence from the Latin American experience
suggests a negative relation between openness and pollution-intensive growth.
In addition, it has been observed that pollution and resource intensity
increased more rapidly in closed economies than in open ones (IMF, Vol II,
1994 quoting Birdsall and Wheeler 1992; Lucas and Hettige 1992). 

25.   Other works point to the important role of the effects of openness in
inducing the adoption and diffusion of clean technology. Similarly, in the
case of Indonesia, it has been shown that liberalisation in the 1980s created
a conducive environment which led assembly-based industries to shift away from
pollution-intensive processing sectors to cleaner ones. This was accompanied
by a rapid movement of industries away from densely populated areas, thus
reducing the health hazards caused by industrial concentration (IMF, Vol.II,
1994 quoting Wheeler and Martin 1992; Birdsall and Martin 1992; Wheeler and
Martin 1993).

26.   Little empirical evidence is available at present on the kinds of
environmental benefits which elimination of trade restrictive and distorting
trade policies might bring. One argument holds that removing or reducing trade
restrictions will not be enough by itself to correct all the environmental
problems to which they contribute. Solving agricultural income problems -
which are linked to environmental problems in the sector - arising from both
domestic and international trade distortions would require the intervention of
three policy measures to take place simultaneously. First, domestic policies
which affect farmers' production negatively should be reformed. Second,
exports of developing countries should have open access to markets in the
developed countries, and the latter should "reduce the level of surpluses and
export subsidies used to dump these surpluses on world markets". These two
reforms which, ultimately, are expected to result in income growth would,
under some assumptions, put developing countries in a better position to apply
the third policy measure, which is protection of "lands sensitive to
environmental damages...from unsustainable practices" (Runge, 1994).

27.   Further empirical studies are required to assess the effects of trade
liberalisation during the implementation process of the Uruguay Round. The
impact of further trade liberalisation on agriculture deserves special
consideration, as distortions would remain high even after full implementation
of the Round (IMF, 1994). A particular area of concern in agriculture is how
trade liberalisation affects the interlinkages between pastoral systems,
forest systems, irrigated land systems and marginal land and the broader
aspects of development (FAO, 1995). Analytical work should focus on the likely
environmental impact of the removal of trade barriers. Similarly, the effect
of liberalisation on price instability is another area which requires further
research (Young and Burton, FAO, 1992). On the question of environmental
subsidies, empirical studies should give consideration to the adequacy of the
Uruguay Round exemptions provided for such subsidies and the utility of
enhancing the exemptions for developing countries (WWF, January 1994). Studies
should be undertaken to analyse the positive and perverse effects on
commodities of the removal of all direct and indirect subsidies that are
detrimental to the environment or threaten biodiversity (Birdlife
International, February 1996). WWF recommends that the combined effects of the
partial reductions in developed country production and export subsidies allied
to new limitations on the use of import controls by developing countries on
food security, the agricultural resource base and the environment in those
countries should be evaluated (WWF, March 1994). 

28.   With regard to tariff escalation, further research on its impact on the
environment of developing countries is required (UNCTAD, TD/B/WG.6/L.7, 1995).
The effects of escalating tariffs and selected non-tariff barriers on
sustainable development is another topic which should be analysed (IISD,
1995). 

                  B. Processes and production methods (PPMs)

      1. Conceptual and practical issues related to PPM-based environmental-
trade measures

29.   PPM-based trade measures are becoming more common as awareness of the
environmental damage being caused by methods of producing is increasing. At
the same time, PPM-based environmental-trade measures also pose a number of
potentially serious problems. First, they present difficult conceptual
problems in trying to distinguish between genuine environmental measures and
protectionist-motivated trade-restrictive practices. Second, they raise the
question of the unilateral imposition by a few economically powerful countries
of higher environmental standards on smaller countries by restricting or
banning their imports unless those smaller countries bring their environmental
policies into line with the importing countries. Third, there is concern that
if unilateral trade measures can be used to frame environmental policies in
other countries, there may be nothing to prevent economically powerful
countries from extending their use of trade measures to other policy goals,
such as labour standards or other social or cultural matters. The two latter
problems have also been raised by trade economists, who have argued that
differential environmental practices, to the extent that they do not affect
the products themselves and to the extent that they do not involve "spill-
over" effects, form part of the comparative advantage equation and are thus
primarily an issue of competitiveness (Stro"m, 1995).

30.   In WTO's terminology, production processes, referred to as PPMs, are of
two types: those which have some effect on the product itself, but which
cannot be detected through inspection, and those which have no effect on the
characteristics of the product itself and relate only to production or
manufacturing process. Regarding the latter, current GATT interpretation, as
expressed in the Tuna/Dolphin panel reports, do not recognize them as
legitimate trade measures in terms of Article III because national treatment
concerns itself with discrimination between "like products". In other words,
if a PPM has no effect on the quality or characteristics of the product, it
cannot be used as a criterion for differentiating between otherwise "like
products" (Dawkins, Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy, 1995). 

31.   The use of import restrictions based on PPMs raises a key trade and
environment issue. The environmental impact of the PPM may be purely local at
the site of production, or it may have transboundary or global environmental
implications. Multilateral trade rules and disciplines make no provision for,
and have been interpreted not to allow for, import restrictions based on
characteristics which are not physically embodied in the imported products and
therefore do not impact on the environment in the importing country (OECD,
COM/ENV/TD(95)48/REV2).

32.   In general, it is impossible to determine the PPMs used to produce a
product by physical inspection of this product at the border. This raises
questions about the feasibility of PPM-related trade restrictions. However,
agreement among relevant countries on verification and certification systems
and mutual recognition of such systems can increase the likelihood of the
feasibility of PPM-related trade restrictions. Verification and certification
systems have in fact been set up for product-related PPM requirements,
primarily in the area of sanitary and phytosanitary measures (OECD, op. cit.).

33.   The cost of verification and certification systems for non-product-
related PPMs can also be higher given the wide diversity of PPMs in various
countries. As in the other cases where verification and certification systems
are established, the cost of the systems and complying with them can create
special difficulties for small producers and exporters, in particular from
developing countries (OECD, op. cit.). Similarly, certification costs weigh
heavily on "organic farmers" in developing countries, especially when they
have to rely on expatriate certifiers. Highly bureaucratic and time-consuming
certification procedures can be a constraining factor on the market, where
flexibility is a precondition of success. Another crucial issue in
certification is credibility. As a rule, consumers must be assured that the
certification mark emanates from an independent source which is not dictated
by the interests of industry or Governments. For developing countries, an
additional concern may arise regarding the competence of their certification
systems as such (UNCTAD/COM, 1996).

34.   The effectiveness of PPM-related trade restrictions in bringing about
specific intended environmental changes in other countries will depend on a
number of factors. These factors include the market power of the country or
countries extending those requirements (e.g. through trade restrictions)
relative to that of the country or countries whose exports are targeted, the
trade dependence of the specific industry whose product or products are
targeted, the volume and direction of trade in the affected product, the type
and combination of instruments used, and the appropriateness and feasibility
of the requirement imposed (OECD, op. cit.).

35.   Since many PPMs can cause environmental degradation, the issue is now
being raised as to whether products produced using environmentally harmful
methods could be identified as such and have trade restrictions placed on
them. Life-cycle assessment (LCA) is an extension of the PPM tool and attempts
to reflect an assessment of the ecological impact of a product during its
whole life. Taking into account upstream and downstream environmental effects
that a product generates, there is already an increasing spread of such
standards and measures relating to the recycling of packaging, return of
containers, used items, etc (International Federation of Agricultural
Producers, 1995). However, effective LCA methodologies are still very much in
the development stages, and many LCAs already carried out have prioritised the
waste disposal stage, while neglecting others. In addition, only a few LCAs
have dealt with the issue of natural resource based products (UNCTAD/COM/70,
1995).

36.   A number of case studies, prepared under UNCTAD's technical cooperation
project sponsored by IDRC provide a preliminary indication of some of the
possible trade effects of eco-labelling in product categories which are of
export interest to developing countries, in particular textiles and footwear.
These studies based on interviews with producers and relevant institutions
illustrate the kind of competitiveness impacts that may arise. These broad
categories include: costs of raw materials; capital costs; costs of testing
and verification; special case of small firms (UNCTAD, TD/B/WG.6/2, 1994).

37.   Eco-labelling could have trade effects. Transparency, which is an
important element in addressing potential adverse trade effects, may also
imply involving developing countries in the eco-labelling process when
products of special export interest to them are concerned (UNCTAD,
TD/B/WG.6/2, 1994). From the developing countries' perspective, the rationale
for establishing eco-labelling criteria for products that are principally
imported has been questioned, in particular when such criteria relate to the
use of specific raw materials or PPMs with local environmental effects
(UNCTAD, TD/B/WG.6/L.7, 1995).

38.   Studies should be undertaken to look for alternative ways to address
PPM-related issues, for example through technology transfer and financial and
technical assistance. Along similar lines, the OECD recommends that the
appropriate and effective role of PPM-based trade restrictions in MEAs needs
to be further explored, as does their relationship with the multilateral
trading system; in addition, work is required on valuing the costs involved in
the use of PPM-based measures compared with the costs of other policy options
considered to be equally feasible and effective (OECD, 1995). According to the
IISD, the WTO should set criteria and prerequisites for such actions based on,
for example, compensation for the loss of expected benefit from negotiated
market access, or acceptance of withdrawal of equivalent trade benefits (IISD,
1995). The Union of Industrial and Employers' Confederations of Europe
recommends more detailed work on the use of economic instruments and
internalisation of environmental costs (UNICE, May 1995). The IISD underlines
the need to address conceptual and methodological issues in relation to
valuation of environmental costs, decision criteria to make the precautionary
principle operational, and appropriate policy and institutional designs (IISD,
1995). There is a need for an international coordinating body to define
legitimate categories and structures for eco-labelling schemes to ensure
multilateral input into the design of new and existing schemes and to
facilitate harmonisation and mutual recognition of standards where appropriate
(IISD, 1995). 

      2. Environmental taxes and border tax adjustments 

39.   The WTO Trade and Environment Committee is, inter alia, analysing the
relationship between GATT and the question of charges and taxes for
environmental purposes. According to some, this begs the question as to
whether the Committee's work would see to it that GATT rules do not conflict
with seemingly neutral taxes imposed on products in support of environmental
or conservation objectives (WWF, September 1994). 

40.   A general interpretation of GATT rules is that border tax adjustments
(BTA) are possible for taxes on products or raw material inputs but not for
taxes on processes. Taxes on production processes, therefore, generate
differences in production costs. The European Chemical Industry Council, for
example, agrees that national environmental problems should be dealt with by
national measures, but expresses concern over environmental problems of a
transboundary or global nature, as national taxes on processes can create
trade distortions. The European Chemical Industry Council proposes that
existing taxes or charges should therefore be harmonised within international
agreements (European Chemical Industry Council, 1994).

41.   Environmental taxes and border tax adjustments are of some concern to
developing countries, and the relationship between BTA and GATT rules raises a
number of controversial issues for trade and environmental policies. First, if
taxes are part of cost internalization measures designed to reduce
environmental damage, their rebate at the border upon export may undermine the
achievement of the environmental goal they were designed to address. Second,
rebating taxes on exports and levying them on imports can reduce the impact of
environmental taxes on competitiveness, creating resistance to changes in the
present rules. Third, the tax rule reinforces the asymmetry between taxes and
regulations under GATT rules, as the costs of compliance with command and
control measures cannot be rebated at the border or imposed on imports.
Fourth, the rules can lead to imports from developing and other countries
being inappropriately subject to environmental standards of industrial
countries. Fifth, the fact that GATT allows border adjustment of product
taxes, but not of process taxes, could lead to sub-optimal environmental
policies (Sorsa, IMF, 1995). 

42.   The border adjustment of environmental taxes is one area in which
present GATT rules may be too "flexible". Any change to the present rules that
would consider environmental objectives of taxes faces measurement and
implementation problems. For instance, application of environmental taxes on
imports, or their rebate on exports, can pose very difficult measurement
problems. If the use of environmental levies increases in the future or more
substantial carbon taxes are introduced, the existing tax adjustment rules may
give rise to trade conflicts (Sorsa, IMF, 1995). It is, however, generally
agreed that border tax adjustments would raise serious competitiveness
concerns if carbon taxes are implemented on a wide scale.

43.   A concern raised by FIELD is to ensure that GATT fully permits border
adjustment fees to compensate for energy or pollution taxes imposed on
domestic industries. In various countries, manufacturers of energy-intensive
products such as chemicals, steel and aluminium have expressed concerns that
payments of energy taxes - taxes on the carbon content of fossil fuel to
reduce greenhouse gas emission - without border adjustments would make them
uncompetitive with foreign firms not subject to comparable taxes (FIELD,
1995). WWF argues that the levying of carbon taxes and other forms of energy
tax will have implications for the price of most tradeable goods and that this
implies that countries taking the lead in the implementation of energy taxes
must have recourse to effective border tax adjustment measures if these
industries are to safeguard their international competitiveness. In addition,
if energy taxes are to prove effective in reducing wasteful consumption of
energy resources and the associated pollution, they must meet certain criteria
which are as follows: taxes must be levied at a level which reduces energy
production and consumption; taxes should be designed in accordance with the
"polluter pays" and "user pays" principles; all power sources should be taxed
on environmental grounds, with the exception of renewable energy sources,
which should be promoted with financial incentives where necessary; all
sectors of industry, including power generation, transport, manufacturing and
agriculture should be taxed; no exemption should apply for energy-intensive
industries; the energy tax should be fiscally neutral within a country;
transfer between countries of revenues raised from energy taxes could be used
to provide the finance and technology necessary to provide energy services at
minimum cost and with least environmental impact on poorer countries (WWF,
September 1994).

                          C. Competitiveness issues 

44.   The issue of environmental requirements and competitiveness is dealt
with in more detail in a separate note, "The relationship of environmental
protection to international competitiveness, job creation and development",
prepared for the fourth session of the CSD by the UNCTAD secretariat
(Background paper # 21).


45.   The traditional hypothesis regarding environmental requirements and
competitiveness is that such requirements adversely affect international
competitiveness, reducing exports from countries with strict regulations.
Another hypothesis is that environmental policies may actually have positive
effects on international competitiveness.  

46.   The first hypothesis is based on the fact that although enhanced
environmental protection generally increases welfare and may also bring
economic benefits, these benefits accrue to the society as a whole rather than
to the regulated firms. By contrast, the costs of increased environmental
protection are usually borne by individual polluters, thus raising private
costs. Examples have been cited where compliance with mandatory and voluntary
environmental requirements has negatively affected the competitiveness of
certain firms and sectors. On the other hand, non-compliance with mandatory
environmental standards can lead to market access problems. For example, there
are several environment-related requirements that Indian agricultural, leather
and textile sectors need to comply with to be able to export to OECD markets
(CUTS 1995).

47.   The question of pollution havens and industrial flight has also been
brought up in the literature. According to Leonard (1988, quoted by IMF,
Vol.II, 1994), differences in pollution control costs between the host
countries and Ireland, Spain, Mexico and Romania were not substantial enough
to alter the investment decisions of multilateral enterprises. Similar results
were obtained by another study for United States investment in Mexico
(Krossman and Krueger, 1991, quoted by IMF, op. cit.). Harrison and Eskeland
(1994) found no evidence in support of the pollution haven hypothesis in Co^te
d'Ivoire, Mexico, Morocco and Venezuela (Harrison and Eskeland, 1994, quoted
by IMF, idem).

48.    A WTO paper (quoting Leonard 1998, Tobey 1990, Grossman and Krueger
1991, Dean 1992, Birdsall and Wheeler 1992, Wheeler and Martin 1992, and Low
1992) points out that there is considerable empirical evidence which
invalidates the view that higher environmental standards make a sufficiently
significant impact on costs of production, inciting most industries to
migrate, and does not support the argument that such migration has in fact
taken place on any significant scale (WTO, WT/CTE/W/1, 1995). For example, in
relation to the effects of NAFTA on Mexico's environment, the alleged
comparative advantage created by lax pollution controls played no substantial
role. Strict environmental regulations imposed in the 1960s and 1970s by
industrial countries did not measurably affect trade patterns in the most
polluting industries. Pollution abatement and control costs of United States
firms are small. There is little evidence of a relationship between
environmental expenditures and trade in environmentally sensitive goods - for
example, pulp and paper, petroleum products, chemicals - defined as the
sectors with the highest pollution abatement costs in the United States in
1988. Furthermore, States with higher pollution abatement controls were not
found to suffer lower export performance (IMF, Vol.I, 1994).

49.   However, there are several examples of firms exporting harmful
industries and technologies as well as hazardous wastes to developing
countries. It is argued that although environmental regulations may not be
among the main driving forces when industrial location decisions are made,
migrating industries sometimes do, nevertheless, use environmentally less
friendly technology in the new host country although the migration decision
itself was made on other grounds. It has also been pointed out that relocation
could be undertaken for purely strategic reasons, to convince policy-makers to
refrain from further tightening of environmental control (Bommer 1995).

50.   A more dynamic approach to analysing the linkages between environmental
requirements and competitiveness tends to emphasise the positive effects
instead, as exemplified by the "Porter hypothesis", which maintains that
strict environmental regulations can in fact improve competitiveness by
resulting in increased efficiency or cost-reducing innovations by firms
(Porter and van der Linde 1995). Furthermore, firms operating within a strict
regulatory environment may gain important first mover advantages in the sector
producing environmental goods and services (EGS), which clearly stands to
benefit from increased environmental protection. 

51.   Several empirical studies have been conducted in OECD countries to test
both competing hypotheses - that environmental regulations have adverse
effects on competitiveness or that they enhance competitiveness (Jaffe et al.
1993). The relationship between the two hypotheses has been analysed by asking
whether: (a) the trade performance of highly regulated sectors has
deteriorated compared to less regulated sectors; (b) production or investment
from highly regulated sectors has moved to countries where regulations are
less stringent; (c) there is a negative correlation between stringency of
environmental regulations and profitability; and (d) basic indicators such as
productivity are adversely affected in relation to firms operating in highly
regulated sectors. 

52.   So far, systematic empirical studies on environmentally related
competitive effects have focused on assessing the impacts of domestic
environmental measures on domestic industries in developed countries. Probably
the first attempt to analyse trade and environment linkages in developing
countries is being undertaken in the context of a series of country case
studies by UNCTAD, in cooperation with UNDP and UNEP. These case studies have
shown that developing country producers are concerned about the potential
adverse impacts of environmental requirements arising from external markets on
their export competitiveness, and brought up specific examples of adverse
competitiveness effects. However, there have also been examples of positive
competitiveness effects of environmental regulations (UNCTAD, TD/B/WG.6/6,
1995).

53.   The literature reveals that no clear links have yet been established
between environmental protection and competitiveness. There is not enough
evidence in support of either hypothesis to justify generalisations. There are
many factors apart from environmental requirements that affect
competitiveness, causing comparative advantage to shift between countries and
the competitiveness of different sectors and firms to vary over time. Given
the complexity of the linkages between environmental protection and
competitiveness, further analysis is necessary. 

54.   There are knowledge gaps regarding the environment-competitiveness
relationship itself. Due to methodological and data limitations in the
existing research, the nature of the linkages between these two is not
resolved. In particular, there has been no systematic identification of
conditions under which competitiveness impacts are likely to be either
positive or negative. 
      
55.   The impacts of environmental regulations on job creation have largely
been overlooked by existing research. Topics that need to be addressed in this
context include the extent to which jobs are likely to move within a country
or between countries because of environmental requirements; whether labour-
intensive sectors would benefit or suffer from environmental regulations; the
specific difficulties of small and medium-sized enterprises in complying with
environmental requirements in the light of their important role in providing
employment; and the role of the EGS sector as a provider of jobs. 

56.   Since most of the existing research has been conducted in the OECD
countries, the development perspective has not received enough consideration.
Taking into account the specific features of developing countries, the
linkages between environmental protection and development through
competitiveness and other impacts should be analysed.

                        D. Harmonisation of standards 

57.   With the growing integration of the world economy, pressures arise for
harmonisation of many policies that may affect international competitiveness,
including environmental policies. Some sectors within industry and labour
favour harmonization as a means to combat import competition and to avoid
migration of pollution-intensive industries to countries with lower standards.
Many environmentalists favour harmonization of process standards as a
guarantee against competing deregulation: from an environmental point of view,
harmonization guarantees a commitment to specified environmental objectives.

58.   Differences in topography, resource endowments, methods of production
and policies, in the broadest sense, exist between all countries; such
differences relate to weather, demography, geography, inherited policies,
technology, wage structure, capital costs, skills, land taxes, etc. The
diversity of standards reflects differences in environmental conditions,
social values or development priorities. Levels of environmental protection
are thus the outcome of the interplay between environmental endowments, actual
environmental pressures and preferences or ability to focus on environmental
quality. 

59.   Because of these complexities, harmonisation of standards might not
necessarily imply globally prevailing equal standards. The question also
arises as to what should be harmonised, using which criteria or whose criteria
- importers' or exporters' - and which instruments at which policy levels
(International Federation of Agricultural Producers, May 1995). 

60.   Support for the harmonisation of environment-related product standards
can be argued for, especially when product standards differ from country to
country and exporters may face significant transaction costs in acquiring
information from many different sources. Similarly, tailoring product
characteristics to meet the unique requirements of many markets may be costly
(International Federation of Agricultural Producers, May 1995). 

61.   Wide variations and rapid changes in regulations, particularly in Europe
and North America, are a cause for considerable confusion and uncertainty for
exporters, who are faced with competing claims concerning, for example,
different pesticide residue levels or packaging types and materials in
different markets. This could be especially burdensome for small producers,
who may need assistance to install equipment or acquire skills necessary to
meet production requirements (International Federation of Agricultural
Producers, May 1995). 

62.   However, increasingly demanding standards are not a new phenomenon for
many exporters. Those who have worked with the European Union and the United
States have accepted the imposition of ever changing and ever stricter
regulations and standards as inevitable (International Federation of
Agricultural Producers, May 1995). 

63.   One point of view of the WWF is that the net environmental effect of any
harmonisation will depend, among other factors, on the standards chosen. The
Codex Alimentarius panel is known to be influenced by multinational food and
chemical companies. Equally important is that harmonisation of environmental
standards could also inhibit innovation of more vigorous environmental
standards (WWF, February 1994).

64.   Because it is generally accepted that a country's solution to domestic
environmental problems should be based on its own policy decisions and
evaluations reflecting its own economic conditions and social preferences,
demands for harmonization of production standards are difficult to justify.
With the exception of processes and production methods that have transborder
environmental impacts or affect the global commons, therefore harmonization of
process standards is not required (UNCTAD, TD/B/40(1)/6, 1993).

65.   Harmonisation of non-product-related PPM requirements on a consensual
basis may be necessary and desirable to address transboundary and global
environmental concerns, whereas it may be less desirable or feasible in the
case of local environmental problems (OECD, COM/ENV/TD(95)48/REV2). For the
European Chemical Industry Council, international harmonisation or convergence
of product requirements based on sound scientific evidence and risk assessment
is desirable, and to this end global harmonisation of product classification
schemes is an essential step. In addition, existing taxes or charges for
regional and global environmental problems should be harmonised within
international agreements (European Chemical Industry Council, December 1994).

66.   The harmonisation of production and processing methods is likely to be a
much more contentious trade issue in the future, since it could involve
conflicting ethical preferences, moral values and the unilateral assertion of
environmental priorities. To avoid such value judgements, the use of objective
scientific criteria has been considered fundamental to any harmonisation of
standards (OECD, 1995).

67.   Research should be based on cases in which harmonisation of standards is
appropriate, as standards cover a wide variety of sectors, all of which
present different obstacles and opportunities for sustainable development
(IISD, 1992).

                E. Multilateral environmental agreements (MEAs)

68.   Multilateral environment agreements (MEAs) constitute an important part
of the environmental management framework. Many observers hold the view that a
number of regional and global issues can only be addressed through these
agreements. Moreover, with the expansion of MEAs, some views are also
expressed as to the likelihood that trade provisions, in some circumstances,
will remain a feature of these agreements (World Business Council for
Sustainable Development, 1995). On the other hand, it has been observed that
"trade measures should not be expected to be a regular feature of MEAs, given
that trade measures are not necessarily the most effective means to achieve
environmental objectives" (WTO, PC/STE/W/3).

      1. Compatibility and consistency of trade measures in MEAs with WTO
rules

69.   The compatibility of trade provisions included in MEAs with GATT's trade
law has been debated, although no actual dispute has ever arisen in this
regard (World Business Council for Sustainable Development, 1995). However,
some of these agreements impose trade restrictions or bans that appear to
contravene GATT principles (Stro"m, 1995).

70.   Other areas requiring clarification have been suggested by many expert
opinions in the literature. For example, in a paper presented to the
Preparatory Committee on Trade and Environment, concerning Multilateral
Environmental Agreements, Greenpeace draws attention to some features of MEAs
which could be subject to challenge under the GATT. Article XX provides
exceptions from the application of GATT provisions to protect human, animal or
plant life or health (Article XX(b)) or relating to the conservation of
exhaustible natural resources (Article XX(g)). Exemption for trade-related
environmental measures under Article XX is possible in some cases, but several
obstacles to its use may arise. First, there may be difficulty in showing that
discrimination against non-signatories is neither arbitrary nor unjustifiable.
Second, the exemption may fail if a regulation applies extraterritorially.
Finally, it may be difficult to show that a measure was "necessary" to protect
life or health under Article XX(b) or "relates to" the conservation of
exhaustible natural resources under Article XX(g) and that no less trade-
restrictive alternative is available (Greenpeace International, 1994).   

71.   In addition, there is another point of conflict in international law
between GATT and MEA regimes which is often raised in this context. Where
conflicts exist between international treaties, for example between a MEA and
GATT, the Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties provides the primary source
for determining which one shall prevail. While all GATT parties are not
parties to the Vienna Convention, GATT parties are bound by the Vienna
Convention where its provisions codify customary international law. Thus, GATT
does not automatically supersede an MEA where a dispute takes place between
two GATT signatories who are also signatories to the MEA which is being
considered (Greenpeace International, 1994).

72.   With regard to possible use of trade measures in MEAs, the following
requirements have been proposed: trade measures should only be used as a last
resort to enforce the provisions laid down; the set objective should not be
attainable by other measures or programmes with a lesser impact on trade;
trade measures should not be unnecessarily restrictive of trade; they must be
clearly related to the environmental objectives of the MEA; they should be
approved by a significant number of signatories, including those who would be
most affected by the trade restrictions; the process which results in trade
measures should be transparent. On the other hand, trade measures against non-
parties to an MEA can be justified if they ensure that all imports or exports
are subjected to the same environmental standards that apply to the
signatories of the agreement (Union of Industrial and Employers'
Confederations of Europe, 1995).

73.   The use of quantitative restrictions in existing MEAs and their
compatibility with the GATT has been summarised by Cameron and Robinson. They
point out that, despite the continuous use of quantitative restrictions in
MEAs - restrictions on exports by parties, restrictions on imports by parties,
restrictions on trade with non-parties - and the policy arguments which
accompany it, only some of these existing restrictions are clearly
incompatible with the GATT. However, it can be argued that a large proportion
are at odds with GATT's basic prohibition on quantitative restrictions, and
that GATT's general exceptions are too narrowly drawn to allow for many
generally accepted and legitimate environmental objectives (Yearbook of
International Environmental Law, Vol. 2, 1991).

74.   With regard to amending the status of the three MEAs under discussion at
the GATT/WTO (Montreal Protocol, Basel Convention and CITES), it has been
suggested that differences in modalities would need to be solved. Generally
speaking, the following possibilities exist: (i) an amendment to the GATT,
stipulating that trade restrictions in conformity with these treaties would be
consistent with the GATT, as in the case of NAFTA which contains such a
provision; (ii) a decision under Article IX(2) of the WTO Agreement
interpreting such restrictions as permissible under Article XX(b) and/or (g)
of GATT; (iii) action under Article IX(3) granting general waivers for
restrictions undertaken pursuant to these treaties. It follows that under the
three modalities, it would be both possible and appropriate to limit the
authorization to restrictions that did not favour domestic production and were
not disguised restraints on international trade (The Consensus Building
Institute, 1995).

75.   In light of the above alternatives, it is argued that an interpretation
of GATT Article XX would be the simplest approach, inasmuch as there is
considerable expert opinion to the effect that restrictions under the three
MEAs are permissible under Article XX as it stands; there can be little doubt
that the action would be a proper exercise of the power of interpretation
granted in WTO Article IX. Furthermore, it has equally been argued that the
use of the waiver technique - which under Article XXV(5) permits the use of a
waiver in exceptional circumstances not elsewhere provided for in the GATT,
where international agreement exists among signatories on the need to use
trade-related environmental measures in an existing and future MEA - would
produce the desired result. However, this may be seen to imply a fundamental
conflict between the proposed restriction and the GATT, which is being waived
only because of "exceptional circumstances". Moreover, a waiver is ordinarily
time-limited and would have to be renewed periodically, after review of the
intervening experience, again implying that the MEA is being accepted only
temporarily and on sufferance (The Consensus Building Institute, 1995;
Greenpeace International, 1995).

      2. Criteria for MEAs

76.   Discussion of the treatment of MEAs that may be negotiated in the future
has focused on the choice between ex ante and ex post approaches. The ex ante
approach would establish criteria for identifying MEAs containing trade
restrictions that would be consistent with the Uruguay Round Agreements. The
criteria might be substantive or procedural or both. Again there would be the
question of the modalities by which such criteria should be adopted, whether
by formal amendment or some kind of decision of the Council. Under the ex post
approach, each MEA authorizing trade restrictions would be submitted, after
being negotiated, for a waiver action under Article IX (The Consensus Building
Institute, 1995).

77.   The International Institute for Sustainable Development (IISD) argues
that until the international community gains more experience with MEAs and
trust levels are built up, MEAs with trade sanctions should seek WTO waivers
on a case-by-case basis, which reflects a measured, flexible approach. The
process to be used in negotiating an MEA and the criteria which would need to
be met so that the MEA qualifies for a waiver should be set out (IISD, 1995).

78.   The need to reach an agreed definition as to what constitutes an MEA
within the context of GATT has been a matter of concern. The procedural
criteria which have been widely proposed as potentially applicable to MEAs
include the following: 

      (a)   The agreement should be open to all relevant least developed,
            developing and developed countries on equitable terms; 

      (b)   The agreement should feature an environmental problem which has
            transboundary or trade-related environmental, conservation or
            human health impacts; 

      (c)   The agreement should be international or regional in scope;

      (d)   The agreement should be for the purpose of protecting human,
            animal or plant life or health or for the conservation of
            exhaustible natural resources;

      (e)   The negotiation of the agreement should be sponsored by the United
            Nations, a United Nations agency, or a responsible regional
            organization, and it should be open to the participation of all
            interested States on equal terms; 

      (f)   Membership should be open to all States affected by the
            environmental problem addressed by the agreement; 

      (g)   The parties adhering to the agreement should account for a
            substantial proportion of the activity regulated by it; 


      (h)   The agreement should take account of the special situation of
            developing countries;

      (i)   The agreement should not unfairly or unnecessarily discriminate
            against non-parties;

      (j)   Trade restrictions contemplated should not constitute a means of
            arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination between countries where
            the same conditions prevail or a disguised restriction on
            international trade.

      (k)   There should be clear and enforceable obligations, including
            dispute settlement procedures;

      (l)   Trade measures used as enforcement mechanisms should be defensible
            on grounds of necessity, effectiveness, proportionality and
            specificity; 

      (m)   There should be a clear definition of what constitutes a
            significant free-rider country to be targeted for punitive
            measures (The Consensus Building Institute, 1995; Greenpeace
            International, 1994; IISD, 1995).

79.   Other suggested criteria concern the "significance" or "importance" of
the environmental problem addressed by the agreement, or whether the trade
restrictions authorized are "necessary" for the achievement of the
environmental objective. But some have questioned whether it would be
appropriate for the WTO to "second-guess" the parties to an MEA that met the
other requirements on matters such as the "importance" of the problem or the
"necessity" of the restrictions (The Consensus Building Institute, 1995). 

80.   The experience with the use of trade measures in the Basel Convention,
the Montreal Protocol and CITES has been diverse. Consequently, it is
difficult to formulate general conclusions drawn from the analysis of a
particular MEA. This suggests that there is a need to analyze carefully the
environmental effectiveness of the use of trade measures on a case-by-case
basis. The World Business Council for Sustainable Development, for example,
argues that the negotiation of an international PPM standard should not become
a basis for downward harmonisation or other forms of lowering of standards.
This puts added pressure to ensure that strategies such as the lowest common
denominator or the averaging of standards are not accepted as a prima facie
basis for any negotiation. Only careful consideration of the merits of each
case should determine the appropriate standard or differentiated standards to
be applied. Trade liberalisation should not become a disincentive for applying
appropriate and effective environmental standards (The World Business Council
for Sustainable Development, 1995).

81.   There is general agreement on the need to integrate environmental
considerations into trade agreements and vice versa. The need to seek
international consensus and coordination to do so is also recognised, as
unilateral trade measures are considered inappropriate to remedy global,
cross-border or national environmental problems. From this standpoint, the use
of trade measures should reflect a genuine multilateral consensus on (a) the
need for environmental measures to be least trade-restrictive; and (b) the
need to ensure that trade measures are least environmentally restrictive
(International Council of Chemical Associations, 1995; European Chemical
Industry Council, 1994; United States Council for International Business,
1993; Greenpeace International, 1994).

82.   Some areas requiring further work have also been indicated. The
necessity and effectiveness of trade measures in MEAs are not easy to
establish, as they form part of a wider framework which can include technology
transfer and technical cooperation, financial elements, differentiated
responsibilities for developing countries and other elements, in addition to
environmental obligations the trade measures are designed to support. Further
work to measure their likely impact on the implementation and enforcement of
these agreements on a case-by-case basis would be useful. The impact of these
provisions on actual trade needs and trade regimes also needs to be
established through empirical studies. Furthermore, in order to bridge the gap
between achieving maximum levels of environmental protection and ensuring an
open trading system free of trade barriers and opportunities for protectionist
and disruptive measures, specific substantive and procedural criteria should
be developed, as suggested by the World Business Council For Sustainable
Development (1995). The OECD argues for the need to develop further
internationally agreed principles to guide the use of trade measures within
the context of MEAs, while avoiding protectionism and disruption of the
trading system, with the objective of reconciling international environmental
law and the multilateral trading system to avoid clashes between the two
systems. Furthermore, the OECD points out the need to promote the effective
implementation of MEAs by stating obligations in these agreements as clearly
as possible and strengthening the provisions on compliance with obligations
for consultation, mediation, conciliation, arbitration or judicial settlement,
as stipulated in a number of these agreements (OECD, 1995). UNCTAD recommends
more research to analyse and evaluate the trade and competitiveness effects of
MEAs. In this context, interim evaluations of MEAs in order to examine such
effects, particularly in the negotiation of future MEAs, are also needed
(TD/B/WG.6/L.7, 1995). Capacity-building efforts should become a standard part
of any MEA, both as incentives for participation and as insurance that
domestic-level efforts at such participation will be as effective as possible
(IISD, 1995).

       E. Trade-related aspects of intellectual property rights (TRIPs)

83.   The Uruguay Round package contains a new agreement on TRIPs, which can
be considered as one of the most ambitious and extensive international legal
agreements ever negotiated on intellectual property rights (WWF, 1995). The
TRIPs Agreement was signed in Marrakesh in April 1994 as part of the Uruguay
Round Final Act. 

84.   The Agreement covers patents, trademarks, copyright and related rights,
geographical indications, layout-designs of integrated circuits, industrial
designs and protection of undisclosed information. It also includes
commitments on national enforcement procedures, as well as multilateral
procedures for the settlement of disputes.

85.   As with all Uruguay Round Agreements, the TRIPs Agreement will be
administered by the WTO and enforced through its Dispute Settlement Body.
However, the Agreement gives Members discretion to determine the "appropriate
method" for implementing the Agreement under their own jurisdictions, although
subsequent provisions appear to circumscribe this discretion by limiting
Member's use of Article 27 exceptions when amending or reconstructing their
legal systems and practices concerning intellectual property rights (WWF,
1995).

86.   The agreement on TRIPs applies the principles of national treatment and
most-favoured-nation treatment to intellectual property rights for the first
time. It also establishes minimum standards - in terms of availability, scope
and use - for patents, copyright, trademarks, geographical origin of products,
industrial designs, layout designs of integrated circuits and trade secrets.

87.   Article 27.2 is the only provision in the TRIPs Agreement that makes an
explicit reference to the environment. It states that "Members may exclude
from patentability inventions, the prevention within their territory of the
commercial exploitation of which is necessary to protect ordre public or
morality, including to protect human, animal or plant life or health or to
avoid serious prejudice to the environment, provided that such exclusion is
not made merely because the exploitation is prohibited by their law". Thus, if
it is necessary to ban the commercial exploitation of an invention in order to
avoid serious prejudice to the environment, a WTO Member is free to refuse a
patent for the invention concerned (WTO, WT/CTE/W/8, 1995).

88.   While the TRIPs Agreement covers all the main areas of intellectual
property, the intellectual property issues that have been raised in the
environment fora concern essentially those IPRs relevant to technology in
particular patents. For example, the importance of promoting environmentally
sound technology has been referred to in many discussions in environmental
fora. A number of provisions of the TRIPs Agreement are of relevance to the
promotion of technological innovation (for example, Article 27.2, Article 39,
Articles 35 to 38). The TRIPs Agreement also contains a number of provisions,
in particular on compulsory licensing and control of anti-competitive
practices, to establish an appropriate balance between these two objectives,
and thus between the interests of producers and users of technological
knowledge, conducive to social and economic welfare (Section 8 of Part II)
(WTO, WT/CTE/W/8, 1995).

      1. Implications for developing countries

89.   The effects of intellectual property protection on the acquisition and
transfer of environmentally sound technologies by developing countries may be
diverse. It is believed by some that better intellectual property protection
could promote the transfer and development of environmentally sound
technologies. On the other hand, the fear of an adverse impact of higher
levels of intellectual property protection on prices and welfare is manifest.
It has also been argued that stronger protection of intellectual property
rights will further widen the gap between North and South, since the North
will be better equipped to have an upper hand in respect of the world's
cutting-edge technology, and that only countries with knowledge-based value
added will benefit from the improvement in the terms of trade (WWF, 1995;
IISD, 1992). Furthermore, failure to uphold TRIPs requirements can lead to the
imposition of substantial penalties, which could mean, among other things,
prohibition of access to Northern country markets of genetically produced
goods or raw materials produced in offending countries (IMF, 1994).
 
90.   According to a paper by the WWF, the TRIPs Agreement affects the
conservation of biodiversity because it will extend and regulate the
commercialization of biological diversity and genetic resources. This
biodiversity is being eroded by the increasing pressure of various human
activities which the Convention on Biological Diversity seeks to alleviate, in
light of which it is argued that the commercial use of biodiversity, which
will be both encouraged and regulated by the TRIPs Agreement, adds
significantly to this pressure (WWF, 1995). 

91.   Another concern stems from the fact that the TRIPs Agreement may
undermine the interests of indigenous people with long-standing knowledge of
biodiversity resources and that revenues thereby derived may not be channelled
back to the respective source areas and human communities (WWF, 1994). As a
matter of fact, the TRIPs Agreement is silent on the question of the
participation of countries/communities in the benefits arising from the use of
technology based on genetic resources originating in their territories. In
this context it is worth noting that in the negotiation of the Biodiversity
Convention, issues related to intellectual rights were important in the
context of provisions dealing with access to and transfer of technology
(Article 166 of the Convention). The role of indigenous and local communities
in conserving biodiversity is recognized in the preamble of the Biodiversity
Convention. The importance of maintaining their knowledge and practices
relevant to the conservation of biodiversity and sustainable use of its
components is also recognised, as is the need to encourage equitable sharing
of benefits derived from their knowledge, innovations and practices (Articles
8(j) and 10(c)) (WTO, 1995). In addition, other arguments hold that any work
the Committee on Trade and Environment undertakes on intellectual property
rights must include in-depth analysis of the legal and institutional
relationships between the WTO regime and the Convention on Biological
Diversity (FIELD, 1995).

92.   Other implications of the TRIPs Agreement for the developing countries
which need to be assessed relate to access to new technologies in the areas of
biotechnology. According to UNCTAD's Trade and Development Report, studies
conducted so far point out that some developing countries "are fairly well-
positioned to promote biotechnological innovation owing to such factors as
climate and geography, which endow them with genetically diverse raw materials
on which the developed countries increasingly depend". It is further argued
that the provision of proprietary rights in this field, including plant
breeders' rights, may contribute to enhancing the competitiveness of a number
of developing countries. In addition to acquiring ownership rights, developing
countries interested in the pursuit of biotechnological innovation need to
preserve their natural genetic endowment for future exploitation. However,
within the short-term perspective, "much biotechnological innovation,
especially processes for making end-products, will fail to meet the non-
obviousness standards of domestic patent laws in industrialized countries.
Such innovations could obtain protection only under a trade-secret law.
Possibilities for reverse engineering are then enhanced by the self-
reproductive properties characteristic of both natural and genetically refined
organisms" (UNCTAD, Trade and Development Report 14 (Supplement), 1994). 

      With regard to the mechanism in place for the protection of plant
varieties, mention should be made of the UPOV (International Association of
Plant Breeders for the Protection of Plant Varieties) Convention, which was
established as a system of protection distinct from patents. The Convention
attempts to deal with the problems of plant breeders' rights holders in
relation to "the limitations that the requirements of the public interest may
impose on the free exercise of such right(s)". "Under the Convention, property
rights are given to plant breeders for improved varieties which possess
characteristics similar to those required for a patentable invention and whose
properties have been improved by human intervention". However, the granting of
exclusive rights to the plant breeder is subject to two exceptions: the right
to save seeds for replanting, and the right to use protected varieties as an
initial source of variation for creating or marketing other varieties that may
be the subject matter of separate and independent protection. One important
point that can be retained here in relation to the TRIPs Agreement is that
"the 1978 and 1991 UPOV Conventions and the patent or effective sui generis
system requirements contained in Article 27(3)(b) of the TRIPs Agreement may
limit "seed sharing" between farmers - a widespread practice in developing
countries - if farmers involved are also engaged in commercial marketing
transactions (i.e. where they sell any agricultural goods produced from the
seeds being shared). This constitutes a powerful disincentive to signing the
UPOV Convention or the TRIPS Agreement" (WWF, June 1995).

94.   A concern highlighted in various discussions on environmental matters is
the need to curb the adverse effects of certain technology on the environment.
Another long-standing subject of attention in most countries has been the
environmental effects of agricultural chemicals, which are generally subject
to a testing and approval procedure before being authorized for marketing. As
far as the TRIPs Agreement is concerned, the main point is that it does not
affect the right of Governments to restrict research or development or the use
of technology on the grounds of protecting the environment. A patent gives the
right to the patent owner to prevent others from using the protected invention
(subject to certain exceptions), but does not guarantee the patent owner the
right to exploit the technology in question.

95.   Research is required to assess the relationship between the TRIPs
Agreement and the Convention on Biological Diversity and the extent to which
the TRIPs Agreement could reduce local and national control over biological
and genetic resources and impair the transfer of environmentally sound
technology to poorer countries (WWF, October 1994 and June 1995). A wide range
of issues related to access to and transfer of technology and the supporting
financial framework which require further enquiries and analysis have been
suggested by OECD. They include access to genetic resources being subject to
national sovereignty; access to and transfer of relevant technologies,
especially in the framework of MEAs, including biotechnology, by those
conserving and providing the genetic resources; and access to benefits
ultimately gained from the use of genetic material in the development of
biotechnology. Other areas of research which need to be probed into include
the impact of IPRs on the environment, with particular emphasis on access to
related technologies and the realization of farmers' rights (OECD, 1995).
Along the same lines, the IISD adds that the effects of IPRs, with reference
to both technology transfer and preservation of biodiversity on sustainable
development, should be analysed (IISD, 1995). 

                         III. PRELIMINARY CONCLUSIONS

96.   This note has attempted to undertake a preliminary review of existing
research on the major issues underlying the trade and environment debate as
they relate to sustainable development. Without claiming to be an exhaustive
analysis of the issues and concerns raised, it has tried to take stock of a
number of issues and suggested areas where greater focus might be necessary in
light of the key policy issues which are likely to be of particular relevance,
mainly to developing countries. 

97.   In general, research efforts should aim at assisting Governments, the
private sector and others in their efforts to make trade and environment
policies mutually supportive in the pursuit of sustainable development. As
called for in Agenda 21, improved access to markets and access to and transfer
of finance and technology are of key importance in assisting developing
countries and countries with economies in transition in meeting the objectives
of sustainable development. In this context, studies are required, for
example, on technology transfer issues and on innovative financing mechanisms
to support developing countries in their efforts to internalize costs.    

98.   Specific subjects most frequently dealt with in studies and other
materials received so far have been grouped, for analytical reasons, in six
areas (chapter II).

99.   Studies on the effects of trade liberalization on the environment can be
subdivided into two groups: (a) studies which analyse the (positive or
negative) environmental effects of trade liberalization and trade expansion;
and (b) studies which analyse the environmental benefits of the reduction or
removal of trade-restrictive or trade-distortive measures. In both cases, more
empirical work is needed to further clarify the relationship. It is to be
noted that policy implications may be different. In the first case, where
trade liberalization has negative environmental effects, there is a need to
complement trade liberalization by sound environmental policies. In the second
case, there is a premium attached to removing trade distorting policies.       
    
100.  With regard to PPMs, many of the studies and statements received refer
to the treatment of PPMs in the WTO. More studies may be needed on the
implications of the use of voluntary instruments based on the life-cycle
approach in the developed countries for the exports of developing countries.
Specific issues which need further research include the question as to whether
the same PPMs yield equivalent environmental benefits across all firms and
industries. In this context, more research is required on concepts such as
mutual recognition and equivalency of divergent environmental standards at an
appropriate level of environmental protection, and that of proportionality
between environmental benefits and economic costs.      

101.  With regard to competitiveness, additional research could focus on the
systematic identification of conditions under which competitiveness impacts
are likely to be either positive or negative. Sectoral studies on
competitiveness effects across countries and across firms will also be
relevant. Further, studies are required on measures which may assist firms in
developing countries to adjust to rapidly changing environmental requirements
in domestic and external markets. Studies are also required to determine cost-
effective ways for developing country firms to enhance environmental
management and, where possible, improve international competitiveness. In this
context, additional research on enterprise development and sustainable
development policies, particularly for SMEs, may be especially relevant.
Studies aimed at assisting developing countries in increasing competitiveness
may also focus on infrastructural development and other enabling factors. 

102.  Most studies and statements on multilateral environmental agreements
(MEAs) refer to the relationship between trade measures pursuant to MEAs and
the rules of the WTO, as well as to the issue of criteria for the use of trade
measures. At the same time, a number of papers express the view that it is
difficult to judge the necessity and effectiveness of trade measures in
achieving the environmental effectiveness of MEAs. 

103.  Additional studies should perhaps focus on proposing a greater range of
more attractive positive measures, in particular innovative instruments to
facilitate financial and technology transfers to developing countries, such as
voluntary mechanisms in the context of foreign investment and technology
transfer and certain market-based instruments.         

104.  An area which is particularly underresearched is the relationship
between intellectual property rights and sustainable development, an issue
which is also relevant in the context of the Convention on Biological
Diversity. Case studies may be required to contribute to a better
understanding of the relationship between IPRs and sustainable development,
particularly in the context of MEAs. Studies are also required to determine
under what circumstances IPRs could be a barrier to the transfer of
environmentally sound technologies and under what circumstances IPRs could
promote such transfers.

105.  Relatively little research appears to have been undertaken on issues
such as domestically prohibited goods and the relationship between development
of the services sector and sustainable development. More research,
particularly empirical research, is required to determine whether existing
instruments in international trade provide enough protection against the
environmentally harmful effects resulting in the recipient country from the
export of domestically prohibited goods. This is particularly relevant in view
of the widely differing capacities for monitoring environmental effects
between the exporting and the importing countries.

      Based on the above, a preliminary conclusion of this note is that more
research may be needed in particular in the following areas: (a) trade
liberalisation and the environment; (b) environmental protection, technology
transfer and trade-related intellectual property rights (TRIPS); (c) trade and
competitiveness effects of environmental policies, including voluntary and
other standards; (d) enterprise development, trade promotion and sustainable
development policies in developing countries; (e) innovative financing
mechanisms to support developing countries in their efforts to internalize
costs; (f) positive measures to address transborder, regional and global
environmental policies, such as incentives to encourage trade in environment-
friendly substitutes, voluntary mechanisms on foreign direct investment and
technology transfer, and market-based instruments; (g) trade and
competitiveness effects of MEAs; and (h) the issue of domestically prohibited
goods. All these issues should be studied with special reference to the
prevailing conditions in developing countries.

107.   This is only a preliminary conclusion. At this early stage of the
preparation of the research paper, it would be inappropriate to make definite
recommendations to the Commission, in particular with regard to the use of
independent expert groups.    

108.  Comments to this paper and additional information are invited from
international organisations, academic institutions, non-governmental
organisations, and other appropriate institutions in developed and developing
countries. These can be addressed to Ms. Leena Alanen, Trade and Environment
Section, UNCTAD, Palais des Nations, 1211 Geneva 10, Switzerland (fax 41-22-
907 0044, e-mail leena.alanen@unctad.org).

REFERENCES

BAIL Angelica: Market-related environmental instruments: a challenge for civil
society in a global economy, NGO Co-operation on Eco-label, Eco-management,
Company environmental reporting and ISO, European Environmental Bureau,
Brussels, 29 November 1995.

BIRDLIFE INTERNATIONAL: Memorandum of evidence to the House of Commons
Environment Committee Inquiry on World Trade and the Environment, Cambridge,
February 1996.

BOMMER Rolf and SCHULZE Gu"nther G.: Economic integration and environmental
policy: Does NAFTA increase pollution? University of Konstanz, Department of
Economics and Statistics, Konstanz, February 4, 1995.

BOMMER, Rolf: Environmental Policy and Industrial Competitiveness: The
Pollution-Haven Hypothesis Reconsidered, University of Konstanz, 1995.

BOOTH Ian: Trade and the environment: Issues for Australian agriculture, A
National Farmers' Federation Discussion Paper, Volume 8, November 1994.

BOURKE I.J: Forest products certification: A background note, FAO, Forest
Products Division, February, 1995.

CAMERON James and RAMSAY Ross: Participation by non-governmental organisation
in the World Trade Organisation, Study No.1: Global environment and trade
study (GETS) - A collaborative enterprise involving the Foundation for
International Environmental Law and Development (FIELD), Yale Centre for
Environmental Law and Policy and the Institute of Agriculture and Trade Policy
(IATP), May 1995.

CAMERON James and de REYA Halina Ward Mishcon: The Multilateral Trade
Organisation - A revised prospective, FIELD, Paper presented for the
International Conference "Striking a green deal": Europe's role in environment
and South-North trade relations (Organised by the Environment and Development
Resource Centre) The European Parliament, Brussels 7-9 November 1993.

CAMERON James and ROBINSON Jonathan: The use of trade provisions in
international environmental agreements and their compatibility with the GATT,
Yearbook of International Environmental Law, Volume 2, 1991, pp.3-30.  

CAMERON James and ROBINSON Jonathan: The use of trade provisions in
international environmental agreements, A report for the OECD prepared by the
Centre of International Environmental Law, (typescript undated). 

CHARNOVITZ Steve AND WICKHAM John: Non-governmental organizations and the
original international trade regime, Off-prints of the Journal of World Trade,
Vol.29, No.5, Geneva, October 1995, pp.111-122.

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES: "Towards sustainability: A European
Community Programme of Policy and Action in relation to the Environment and
Sustainable Development", COM (92), Brussels, 27 March 1992.

THE CONSENSUS BUILDING INSTITUTE INC.: Policy Dialogue on Trade and
Environment, MEMO (from Abraham Chayes, Lawrence Susskind and Jan Martinez),
Cambridge, Massachusetts, July 13, 1995.

CUTS (Consumer Unity & Trust Society): Environmental Conditions in
International Trade - Impact on India's exports in the area of textiles and
garments including carpets, leather and leather goods, agricultural and food
products including tea, and packaging. A study for the Central Pollution
Control Board, Ministry of Environment & Forest, Government of India, Delhi,
1995.

DAWKINS Kristin: Ecolabelling: Consumers' right-to-know or restrictive
business practice? Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy, revised
September 25, 1995.

EUROPEAN CHEMICAL INDUSTRY COUNCIL (CEFIC): Trade and Environment - Free-trade
and environmental protection, Position Paper, Brussels, 22 December 1994.

FOOD AND AGRICULTURAL ORGANISATION (FAO): Summary of points relating to forest
products certification arising from recent FAO meetings, prepared on 16 June
1995.

FAO: International trade, environment and sustainable agricultural
development: A progress Report, Item 6 (i) of the Provisional Agenda,
Committee on Commodity Problems, Sixtieth Session, Rome, 3-7 April 1995.

FAO: The grains sector and the environment: Basic issues and implications for
trade, Item II.C of the Provisional Agenda, Committee of Commodity Problems,
Twenty-Sixth Session, Rome, 30 May-2 June 1995, CCP:GR 95/3, February 1995.

FAO: Environmental concerns and the world oilseeds economy: Basic issues and
implications for trade, Point III (C) of the Provisional Agenda, Committee on
Commodity Problems, Intergovernmental Group on Oilseeds, Oils and Fats, 27th
Session, Rome 9-12 May 1995, CCP: OF 95/3, March 1995.

FAO: The livestock sector and the environment: Basic issues and implications
for trade, Committee on Commodity Problems, Intergovernmental Group on Meat,
Fifteenth session, 3-6 October 1994, CCP: ME 94/5, July 1994.


FAO: The impact of the Uruguay Round and other measures affecting wine trade,
Committee on Commodity Problems, Intergovernmental Group on Wine and Vine
Products, Sixth Session, Santiago, 5-9 September 1994, CCP: WI 94/8, July
1994.

FAO: Report of the International Consultation on Jute and the Environment, The
Hague, 26-29 October, 1993, ESC: JU/IC 93/28, December 1993.

FAO: Committee on Commodity Problems - Intergovernmental Group on Jute, Kenaf
and allied Fibres, Twenty-ninth Session, Rome, 6-8 December 1993, Main
conclusions of the International Consultation on Jute and the Environment,
CCP: JU 93/7, December 1993.

FAO: International trade, environment and sustainable development, Committee
on Commodity Problems, Fifty-Ninth Session, Rome, 7-11 June 1993.

FAO: International trade, environment and sustainable agricultural
development, Committee on Commodity Problems, Fifty-Ninth Session, Rome, 7-11
June, 1993, CCP: 93/19, March 1993.

FILHOL Agne`s: Impact of the Uruguay Round on international fish trade,
GLOBEFISH, FAO, GLOBEFISH Research Programme, Volume 38, July 1995.

FOUNDATION FOR INTERNATIONAL ENVIRONMENTAL LAW AND DEVELOPMENT (FIELD):
Natural resources and international dispute settlement - A conference Review,
Frere Cholmeley Bischoff, Paris, February 1994.

FRIENDS OF THE EARTH: Intellectual Property Rights and the Biodiversity
Convention: The impact of GATT, London, May 1995.

GENERAL AGREEMENT ON TARIFFS AND TRADE (GATT): Interim Report, 3 December
1992.

GRAY and SHADBEGIAN: Environmental Regulation and Manufacturing Productivity
at the Plant Level, NBER Working Paper No. 4321, 1993.

GREENPEACE INTERNATIONAL: Comments on the European Community submission on the
GATT and the trade provisions of Multilateral Environmental Agreements (MEAs)
(TRE/W/5) 17 November 1992, prepared for submission to The Committee on Trade
and Environment Multilateral Environmental Agreements (MEAs), July 1995,
revised edition. 

GREENPEACE INTERNATIONAL: Correcting potential conflicts between multilateral
environmental agreements and GATT 1994, prepared for consideration by GATT
members attending the October 26-27 WTO Preparatory Committee Trade and
Environment Committee Meeting concerning Multilateral Agreements (MEAs)
(undated).


HANSEN Michael and RUUD Audun: Transnational corporate environmental
management, Centre for Development and the Environment (SUM), University of
Oslo, Working Paper 1995.4.

HUDSON J. Stewart and PRUDENCIO Rodrigo J.: Report of the North American
Commission on Environment and other supplemental agreements: Part Two of the
NAFTA Package, Washington, D. C., February 4, 1993.

HVEEM Helge: Power, promises and the potential of the WTO - The Uruguay Round
and the developing countries, Draft of the final report, Universitetet I Oslo,
Senter for Utvikling, Miljo (SUM), June 1995.

INTERNATIONAL CHAMBER OF COMMERCE: International trade and the environment:
Principles for policy and implementation, Commission on International Trade
Policy, Policy and programme Department, Document No. 103/160 Rev., Paris, 3
October 1991.

INTERNATIONAL COUNCIL OF CHEMICAL ASSOCIATIONS: Position Paper on Sustainable
Development, Washington, D.C., 3 October 1995.

INTERNATIONAL COUNCIL OF CHEMICAL ASSOCIATIONS: Position Statement on trade
and Environment, Washington, D.C., 11 April 1995.

INTERNATIONAL COUNCIL OF CHEMICAL ASSOCIATIONS: Position Statement on Product
Requirements, Washington, D.C., 11 April 1995.

INTERNATIONAL COUNCIL OF CHEMICAL ASSOCIATIONS: Position Statement on
Production and Process Methods, Washington, D.C., 11 April 1995.

INTERNATIONAL COUNCIL OF CHEMICAL ASSOCIATIONS: Position Statement on Green
Dumping, Washington, D.C., 11 April 1995.

INTERNATIONAL COUNCIL OF CHEMICAL ASSOCIATIONS: Position Statement on the use
of Trade Measures for Environmental Purposes, Washington, D.C., 11 April 1995.

INTERNATIONAL FEDERATION OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCERS: Trade and Environment,
IFAP Conference on Commodities, Trade and the Environment, Washington DC, 17-
18th May 1995, Working Document prepared by the IFAP Secretariat.

INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT (IISD): GATT, the WTO and
sustainable development - Positioning the work program on trade and
environment, Winnipeg, Manitoba, Canada, 1995.

INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT (IISD): Delivering
sustainable options to decision-makers, IISD Annual Report 1994-1995,
Winnipeg, Manitoba, Canada, undated.

INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT (IISD): Trade and
sustainable development - A survey of the issues and a new research agenda,
Winnipeg, Manitoba, Canada, 1992.

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND: International trade policies - The Uruguay Round
and beyond, Volume I. Principal issues, World Economic and Financial Surveys,
prepared by a staff team led by Naheed Kirmanin, Washington, D.C., 1994.

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND: International trade policies - The Uruguay Round
and beyond, Volume II. Background papers, World Economic and Financial
Surveys, prepared by a staff team led by Naheed Kirmanin, Washington, D.C.,
1994.

JAFFE, Adam B., PETERSON Steven R., PORTNEY Paul R., and STAVINS Robert N.:
"Environmental regulations and international competitiveness: What does the
evidence tell us?" Washington, D.C., Resources for the Future Discussion
Paper, December 1993.

LALONDE Bruce and CHABASON Lucien: Toward an ecological injection into
international trade, Eco-De'veloppement, Paris, Second edition, Revised April,
1994.

MARKANDYA, Anil (edited by): Policies for sustainable development - Four
essays, FAO Economic and Social Development Paper 121, FAO, Rome, 1994.

NATIONAL FARMERS' FEDERATION: Farm forestry - A sustainable growth industry,
Down To Earth, An analysis of environment issues by the National Farmers'
Federation, Australia, Issue No. 3, June 1995.

NATIONAL FARMERS' FEDERATION: Greenhouse: A national sink enhancement strategy
- The rural sector's approach provides multiple benefits, An analysis of
environment issues by the National Farmers' Federation, Australia, Issue No.
2, March 1995.

NATIONAL FARMERS' FEDERATION: Greenhouse - What does it mean for the rural
sector, Down To Earth, An analysis of environment issues by the National
Farmers' Federation, Australia, Issue No. 1, November 1994.

NATURAL RESOURCES DEFENSE COUNCIL, Inc., FOUNDATION FOR ENVIRONMENTAL LAW AND
DEVELOPMENT: Environmental priorities for the world trading system -
Recommendations to the WTO Committee on Trade and Environment, Washington,
D.C., 1995.

NATIONAL WILDLIFE FEDERATION: (Various package hand-outs and statements on
environment, trade and sustainable development, Washington, 1991-1994).

ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT (OECD): Draft 1995
Report to Ministers on trade and environment, Environment Policy Committee,
Trade Committee, Paris, 27 April 1995.

ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT (OECD): Joint Report on
Trade and Environment, 1991. 

PORTER, M. and VAN DER LINDE C.: "Green and Competitive", Harvard Business
Review, September-October 1995, pp. 120-134.

PRUDENCIO Rodrigo J. and HUDSON Stewart J.: The road to Marrakech: An interim
report on environmental reform of the GATT and the international trade system,
National Wildlife Federation, International Programs Division, Washington,
D.C., January 25, 1994.

RAFI KHAN Sharukh Rafi: Trade liberalisation and the environment: A view from
the South, Sustainable Development Policy Institute, Islamabad, Conference on
Green Economics, Islamabad, September 12-14, 1995. 

REPETTO, R.: Jobs, Competitiveness and Environmental Regulation: What are the
Real Issues?, World Resources Institute, 1995.

RUUD Audun: Corporate environmental decision-making: a rational choice? Centre
for Development and the Environment (SUM), University of Oslo, Working paper
1995.2. 

SCHOLZ Imme and WIEMANN Ju"rgen: Ecological requirements to be satisfied by
consumer goods - a new challenge for developing countries' exports to Germany,
German Development Institute, Berlin, June 1993.

SORSA Piritta: Environmental protectionism, North-South Trade, and the Uruguay
Round, IMF Working Paper, International Monetary Fund Office in Geneva, 1995.

STRo"M Torsten H.: Trade and the environment: An analysis of recent efforts to
reconcile the GATT and international environmental protection. A research
paper submitted in partial fulfilment of the degree of Master of Laws in
international and comparative law, Faculty of Law, Vrije Universiteit Brussel,
Brussels, 1995.

UNION OF INDUSTRIAL AND EMPLOYERS' FEDERATIONS OF EUROPE (UNICE): UNICE
additional comments on Trade and Environment, 9 November 1995.

UNION OF INDUSTRIAL AND EMPLOYERS' FEDERATIONS OF EUROPE (UNICE): Preliminary
UNICE contribution to preparation of the Community green paper on
international trade and environment, 20 May 1994.

UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT (UNCTAD): Organic
production in developing countries: potential for trade, environmental
improvement, and social development, Report prepared by the UNCTAD
Secretariat, UNCTAD/COM, 7 February 1996 (draft).

UNCTAD: Final Report of the Ad Hoc Working Group on Trade, Environment and
Development, Trade and Development Board Ad Hoc Working Group on Trade,
Environment and Development, Third session, Geneva, 6 November 1995,
TD/B/WG.6/L.7, 22 November 1995.

UNCTAD: Environmentally preferable products (EPPs) as a trade opportunity for
developing countries, Report by the UNCTAD Secretariat, UNCTAD/COM/70, 19
December 1995.

UNCTAD: The policy debate on trade, environment and development, Environment,
international competitiveness and development: Lessons from empirical studies,
Trade and Development Board Ad Hoc Working Group on Trade, Environment and
Development, Third session, Geneva, 6 November 1995, Item 2 of the provisional
agenda, Report by the UNCTAD Secretariat, TD/B/WG.6/10, 12 September 1995.

UNCTAD: Trends in the field of trade and environment in the framework of
international cooperation, UNCTAD's contribution within its mandate to
sustainable development, Trade and Development Board, Fortieth session, First
part, Item 4 of the provisional agenda, Report by the UNCTAD Secretariat,
TD/B/40 (1)/6, 6 August 1993.

UNCTAD: Environmental policies, trade and competitiveness: conceptual and
empirical studies, Effects of environmental policies, standards and
regulations on market access and competitiveness, with special reference to
developing countries, including with least developed among them, and in light
of UNCTAD empirical studies, Trade and Development Board, Ad Hoc Working Group
on Trade, Environment and Development, Second session, Geneva, 6 June 1995,
Item 3 of the provisional agenda, Report by the UNCTAD Secretariat,
TD/B/WG.6/6, 29 March 1995.

UNCTAD: Eco-labelling and market opportunities for environmentally friendly
products, International Cooperation on Eco-labelling and Eco-certification
Programmes and Market Opportunities for Environmentally Friendly Products,
Trade and Development Board, Ad Hoc Working Group on Trade, Environment and
Development, First session, Geneva, 28 November 1994, Item 3 and 4 of the
provisional agenda, Report by the UNCTAD Secretariat, TD/B/WG.6/6, 6 October
1994.

UNCTAD: The outcome of the Uruguay Round: an initial assessment, Supporting
Papers to the Trade and Development Report, 1994, UNCTAD TDR 14/Supplement.

UNCTAD: World Investment Report 1992, Transnational corporations as an engine
of growth.

UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON ENVIRONMENT AND DEVELOPMENT (UNCED): Agenda 21.

UNITED NATIONS INDUSTRIAL DEVELOPMENT ORGANIZATION (UNIDO): Report of the
Expert Group Meeting on the Potential effects of ISO 9000 and ISO 14000 Series
and Environmental Labelling on the Trade of Developing Countries, Vienna, 23-
25 October 1995.

UNITED STATES COUNCIL FOR INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS: State of the United States
Council for International Business on constraints on the unilateral use of
trade measures to enforce environmental policies, New York, April 8, 1994.

UNITED STATES COUNCIL FOR INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS: Statement of the United
States Council for International Business on constraints on International
Environmental Agreements and the use of trade measures to achieve their
objectives, New York, December 15, 1993.

UNITED STATES COUNCIL FOR INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS: State of the United States
Council for International Business on An integrated approach to environment
and trade issues and the GATT, New York, 
May 1, 1992.

United States, Office of Technology Assessment: Industry, Technology and the
Environment: Competitive Challenges and Business Opportunities, Appendix A,
OTA-ITE-586, 1994.

WESTKOG Hege: The use of cost-benefit analyses to decide environmental policy
- a dead end? Centre for development and the Environment, University of Oslo,
Norway, Draft, August 30, 1995.

WIEMANN Ju"rgen et al.: Ecological product standards and requirements as a new
challenge for developing countries' industries and exports - The case of
India's leather, textile and refrigeration industries, German Development
Institute, Berlin, 1994.

WIEMANN Ju"rgen: Environmentally oriented trade policy: A new era of conflict
between North and South?, German Development Institute, Berlin, September
1992.

WINPENNY James and WILLIS Robert: Economic assessment of product-related
environmental impacts, Commodity Policy and Projections Service, Commodities
and Trade Division, FAO, Rome, 1995.

WORLD BUSINESS COUNCIL FOR SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT: Trade and environment: A
business perspective, Draft August 1995.

WORLD COMMISSION ON ENVIRONMENT AND DEVELOPMENT: Our common future, 1987.

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION (WTO): Environment and Trips, Committee on Trade and
Environment, WT/CTE/W/8, June 1995.

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION (WTO): Environmental benefits of removing trade
restrictions and distortions, Committee on Trade and the Environment, Note by
the Secretariat, WT/CTE/W/1, 16 February 1995.

WORLD WIDE FUND FOR NATURE (WWF): Taxes for environmental purposes: The scope
for border tax adjustment under WTO rules, A WWF International Discussion
Paper, Gland, Switzerland, October 1995.

WWF: EU participation in the World Trade Organisation: Implications for trade
and environment issues of the New Code of Conduct, WWF European Briefing, WWF,
Gland, Switzerland, March 1995.

WWF: The UN Biodiversity Convention and the WTO TRIPS Agreement, A WWF
International Research Report, World Wide Fund for Nature, Gland, Switzerland,
June 1995.

WWF: The European Union: Ratification of the Uruguay Round and participation
in the World Trade Organization, WWF European Briefing, WWF, Gland,
Switzerland, November 1994.

WWF: Terms of reference for an assessment: Impact of the Uruguay Round
Agreement on environment and sustainable development, WWF, October 1994.

WWF: Environmental taxes and charges and border tax adjustment - GATT rules
and energy taxes, A critique for the World Wide Fund for Nature, WWF, Gland,
Switzerland, September 1994.

WWF: Sustainable development and integrated dispute settlement in GATT 1994, A
WWF International Research Report, World Wide Fund for Nature, Gland,
Switzerland, June 1994.

WWF: Joint statement by OXFAM and the World Wide Fund For Nature on the
conclusion and ratification of the GATT Uruguay Round Agreement, WWF
International, March 1994.

WWF: South- North terms of trade, environmental protection, and sustainable
development. A WWF International Discussion Paper, World Wide Fund for Nature
(WWF), Gland, Switzerland, (revised) February 1994.

WWF: The GATT Trade and Environment Work Programme - A joint NGO Statement,
WWF International, Gland, Switzerland, 9 February 1994.

WWF: The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, Environmental Protection, and
Sustainable Development, A WWF International Discussion Paper, World Wide Fund
for Nature (WWF), Gland, February 1994.

WWF: Green protectionism, A WWF International Discussion Paper, World Wide
Fund for Nature (WWF), Gland, February 1994.

WWF: The GATT Trade and Environment Work Programme, WWF Position Statement,
WWF, Gland, Switzerland, January 1994.

WWF: Necessity and proportionality - The search for an environmental
definition - A Critique by the WWF-World Wide Fund for Nature of the European
Community's submission to the GATT Working Group on Environmental Measures and
International Trade, TRE/W/5, 17 November 1992, WWF, Gland, Switzerland, June
1993.

WWF: WWF position statement on the Multilateral Trade Organization, WWF,
Gland, Switzerland, May 1993.

WWF: The Uruguay Round's Technical Barriers to Trade Agreement, A WWF
International Research Report, World Wide Fund for Nature, Gland, Switzerland,
January 1993.

WWF: The Multilateral Trade Organization: a legal and environmental
assessment, A WWF International Research Report, WWF, Gland, Switzerland,
September 1992.

WWF (organised by): Proceedings - The forest sector under the North American
Free Trade Agreement, International Workshop, Oaxaca, Mexico, August 6, 1992.

WWF: International trade, GATT, and the environment, A WWF International
Discussion Paper, World Wide Fund for Nature (WWF), Gland, May 1992.

WWF: Conservation and sustainable management of tropical forests: The role of
WTO and GATT, A WWF International Discussion Paper, World Wide Fund for Nature
(WWF), Gland, reprinted February 1992.

YOUNG T. and BURTON M.P.: Agricultural sustainability: definition and
implications for agricultural and trade policy, FAO Economic and Social
Development Paper 110, FAO, Rome, 1992.


                                     Notes

1/          Official Records of the Economic and Social Council, 1995,
Supplement No. 12 (E/1995/32).

2/          The request for information was sent to international
organizations, academic institutions and NGOs that had participated in the
GATT Symposium on Trade, Environment and Sustainable Development in 1994.

 


This document has been posted online by the United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs (DESA). Reproduction and dissemination of the document - in electronic and/or printed format - is encouraged, provided acknowledgement is made of the role of the United Nations in making it available.

Date last posted: 3 December 1999 10:27:35
Comments and suggestions: DESA/DSD